bilaterals.org logo
bilaterals.org logo
   

Bilateral trade agreements and the world trading system

Bilateral Trade Agreements and the World Trading System [*]

by
Jayant Menon, Asian Development Bank Institute, Tokyo

Bilateral Trade Agreements (BTAs) have been proliferating. Why are they so popular? What are their impacts on multilateralism and the world trading system? This papers attempts to answer these questions. First we identify the general and specific factors driving the growth in BTAs. Next we examine how BTAs in general, and different types of BTAs, are affecting the world trading system. Although the sheer number of BTAs is fragmenting the world trading system, the impact of individual BTAs often depends on their underlying motivation. Finally, we consider likely scenarios for the future landscape of world trade, and possible responses.

November 2006


Abstract

The interest in forming BTAs has been growing at a phenomenal rate. In the Asia-Pacific region alone, the number of BTAs has more than tripled over the past 5 years, from 57 in 2002 to 176 in October 2006. There are more than 300 worldwide. In this paper, we try to explain the proliferation of BTAs by identifying the underlying motivations behind them. We identify a set of general and specific factors involved. The general factors related to disenchantment with progress of the WTO; snowballing and domino effects as a result of countries not wanting to be left behind; lower visibility and thus lower resistance from opposing forces; and pure politics driven directly by politicians or political parties. There are three broad categories of specific factors that we identify: economic; strategic and event driven. Each are further divided into sub-categories and in total we identify 11 specific factors to explain the proliferation of BTAs.

Next we look at the impact of BTAs on multilateralism and the world trading system. In general, it is would appear that the sheer number of BTAs and their continued rapid growth is fragmenting the world trading system. The most obvious effect is the much discussed spaghetti-bowl effect. It is also distracting, and drawing scarce resources away from the multilateral effort. But the story is not that simple or straight-forward once we consider specific factors. The fallacy of division applies because the motivation in pursuing a BTA can determine if its impact on the world trading system is positive or negative. Most of the event driven BTAs appear to either support multilateralism or have a positive effect on the world trading system. All of the strategically motivated BTAs appear to have a negative effect. Of the economically motivated BTAs, sector expanding and market restoring BTAs have the potential of supporting the multilateral process, while market creating and sector excluding BTAs appear to threaten it.

Finally, we look at what the future might hold. Are BTAs likely to continue proliferating? It seems that they will until the world trading system is so distorted that countries will be forced to seek a remedy. This response may take several forms.

One is the consolidation of BTAs into region-wide PTAs, or blocks, where the various BTAs between members belonging to the same region become largely redundant. For instance, an Asia-wide FTA would supersede a host of regional BTAs and consolidate them into one region-wide agreement. Although this may reduce the number of intra-regional BTAs, it may serve to further fragment the world trading system by carving it up into distinct regional blocks. Furthermore, it may provide fresh impetus for a new wave of market restoring BTAs as traditional trade partners outside the region seek to retain trade access with members of the consolidated PTA. In fact, with more countries outside the region that inside, it is possible that the total number of BTAs could actually increase. Thus, consolidation through region-wide PTAs is not the remedy to the problems facing the world trading system.

The second response may come in the form of the completion of the Doha round with minimum compromises. A bona fide conclusion to the Doha Round should dilute preferences that are currently scattered around the world, and take away much of the incentive to continue pursuing BTAs. If this happens, then the proliferation of BTAs would have contributed to their eventual demise, in terms of their impact on the world trading system. This is much more like a remedy to the problems facing the world trading system.

But what is the Doha round fails, or is concluded in such a watered-down form that its impact is minimal? Although this may provide an additional incentive to pursue more BTAs and PTAs, there may eventually come a point where countries may voluntarily seek a remedy that lies in their own best interests. Not only is the cost of administering and implementing multiple country-specific BTAs high, it rises with the number of BTAs. Once a country has concluded BTAs with most of its major trading partners, it makes sense to: equalize preferences across these BTAs and offer them to non-BTA countries on an MFN basis. This would remove the administrative burden, and eliminate distortions to country and global trade patterns. As it is with reversing much of second-best policies, it is the actual realized cost of implementation rather than any potential unrealized benefits that usually drives the process. And there are significant potential unrealized benefits that will accrue to the country concerned as well as the world trading system if this process of multilateralizing preferences is pursued, whatever the reason.

Bilateral Trade Agreements and the World Trading System

1. Introduction

On 15 August 2004, Mongolia signed a Trade and Facilitation Agreement (TIFA) with the US, a precursor to a Bilateral Trade Agreement (BTA). Prior to this, Mongolia was the only country that had not signed either a TIFA or BTA with another country, or joined a regional or plurilateral trade agreement (PTA). Every country in the world today is a member of at least one PTA and BTA, and most are members of multiple BTAs. If PTAs were considered the main threat to the world trading system in the 1990s, the concern has since shifted towards BTAs. BTAs have been proliferating at an astounding pace recently.

What are the underlying factors driving the proliferation of BTAs? Why are Japan and Korea, countries that had had long resisted the worldwide trend to join or form PTAs, now pursuing BTAs with a vengeance? Can we explain why Singapore is currently negotiating a BTA with Kuwait, or why Sri Lanka has signed one with Iran, or Taipei,China with Nicaragua, for that matter? Indeed, what are the motivations behind the 176 BTAs currently being proposed, negotiated or implemented involving at least one country from the Asia-Pacific region, or the 300 or so BTAs world-wide?

This paper attempts to provide an answer to these questions by providing a taxonomy of BTAs, identifying the underlying motivations behind them in terms of both economic and non-economic factors. Apart from trying to understand why BTAs have been proliferating, identifying the factors driving them is important because they may reveal the impact that they are having on the world trading system. Depending on why countries form BTAs, they could be working as either building blocks or stumbling blocks in terms of a more integrated and successful international economy.

The paper is in 5 parts. Section 2 provides some facts and figures relating to BTAs, including their proliferation, to provide the backdrop for the ensuing analysis. Section 3 provides a taxonomy of BTAs, identifying the different reasons that motivate countries to form them. The impact that BTAs are having on multilateralism and the world trading system is the subject of Section 4. A final section provides a summary of main points, and considers likely scenarios for the future landscape of world trade, and possible responses.

2. BTAs: Some facts and Figures

It is useful to start by defining what is meant by a BTA. A BTA can vary by nature of the members involved and by nature of the agreement. Most BTAs are between (two) countries, but a BTA can also be signed between a country and a PTA, a BTA and a PTA, or between two BTAs or PTAs. Furthermore, one or even both parties to the BTA need not be a country or a BTA or PTA. There are three entities that are currently recognized as members of the WTO but are not recognized as independent countries: these are The European Communities; Macao, China; and Hong Kong, China. Macao, China has a BTA with the People’s Republic of China (PRC) and the European Union (EU), while Hong Kong, China has a BTA with the PRC and is in negotiations with New Zealand.

The most common type of bilateral agreement is a free trade agreement (FTA), although it can also take the form of a Customs Union (CU) or a services agreement. A bilateral CU is rare and a services agreements tends to be accompanied by an FTA.

Table 1 provides a chronological summary of BTAs and PTAs involving at least one country from the Asia-Pacific region. The same information is provided in diagrammatic from in Figure 1. A complete listing of the BTAs that involve at least one country from the Asia-Pacific region, together with their status, is provided in Table 2. As of October 2006, there were 176 BTAs.
As Figure 1 highlights, the number of BTAs doubled between 1995 and 2000, but has increased more than four-fold between 2000 and 2006. Every country, with the exception of Mongolia, is involved in at least 1 BTA. India heads the list with 22 BTAs, although most of these have yet to be implemented. The US comes in second with 20 BTAs, half of which are already under implementation. Singapore and Pakistan are tied in third place with 19 BTAs each. The latecomers to PTAs, Japan and Korea, have caught up on preferential arrangements through BTAs it would seem, and are involved in 17 and 15 of them, respectively.

Figure 1
BTAs and PTAs of Asia-Pacific Countries (up to October 2006)

Source: Table 2.

Out of the 176 BTAs, 155 are between countries. Two of them involve the SARs and the remaining 19 involved either a PTA and\or a BTA. There are 7 PTAs and a BTA that are party to at least one BTA in the Asia-Pacific region. The BTA concerned is the Australia-New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Agreement (ANZCER), which is negotiating a BTA with ASEAN. Apart from ASEAN, the other 6 PTAs involved in BTAs are: EFTA; EU; Gulf Cooperation Council; MERCUSOR; NAFTA; and South African Customs Union.

Fifty two of the 176 BTAs, or about 30 percent, are already being implemented. Twenty eight BTA agreements have been signed but implementation has yet to commence; in some cases, legislative or executive ratification is required before implementation can begin. Another 30 percent are currently under negotiation, a quarter of which have also signed a Framework Agreement before proceeding. A quarter of the BTAs are still at the proposal stage, where consultation and study are on-going to determine whether the BTA should proceed.

3. Why are BTAs So Popular?

The first thing to note when discussing the popularity of BTAs relates to possibilities, or the maximum number that are technically possible. In theory, it is possible to have many more BTAs than PTAs simply because only two entities are involved and there are no geographical (regional) restrictions on membership. With 192 countries in the world (excluding the Vatican and Holy See), and two non-country members of the WTO, it is technically possible to have up to 18,721 BTAs (194 times 193 divided by 2) between them! If we include BTAs between a country and a PTA, a BTA and a PTA, or between PTAs, then this number becomes even bigger. Adding the 7 PTAs and 1 BTA that have already engaged in BTAs raises the maximum number to 20,301. Of course there are many more than 7 PTAs and any of them could start negotiating BTAs in the future. Furthermore, the possibility exists for new PTAs to be formed in the future, that could then participate in BTAs as well, and there is nothing stopping BTAs from forming new BTAs between themselves, and so on and so forth! All of this does not explain why BTAs are popular of course, but they do suggest that if they are, then they can proliferate in a dramatic and almost uncontrollable way, unlike other forms of PTAs.

So what are the factors driving the proliferation of BTAs in the world today? In answering this question, we identify a set of general as well as specific factors or motivations for the popularity of BTAs. The general motivations apply to most, if not all BTAs, but there is always at least one additional specific factor that drives the formation of a BTA. Usually there is more than one specific factor involved however. For instance, each party to the BTA may have their own motivation in pursuing the agreement, and this may not coincide with the interest of the other party. It is also possible that each party has more than one motivating factor in pursuing the BTA.

 3.1 General factors

An important general reason for the popularity of BTAs is the apparent disenchantment with pace of progress with liberalization at the multilateral level. The difficulties associated with concluding the Doha round have simply reinforced this view. Many feel that the WTO has failed to deliver and so have pursued BTAs (and PTAs) as a means of pressing ahead with their trade and liberalization agendas.

A kind of snowballing or domino effect, as with PTAs in the past (see Baldwin 1996), has also been driving the growth in BTAs. In the Asia-Pacific region, interest in forming BTAs began in the late 1990s with Japan, Singapore, South Korea and New Zealand initially. By 2000, the US, Australia, Thailand and the PRC had joined the trend, with more than 40 new BTAs being proposed or negotiated (see Table 2). The momentum gathered over subsequent years to the point where other Asia-Pacific countries may have felt disadvantaged if they did not join the club. The number of BTAs thus continued to grow, and almost doubled to 109 between 2002 and 2004. It is quite possible that it may double again by the end of 2006. There is clearly a momentum effect driving some of the growth in BTAs with countries not wanting to be left behind in this apparent race. Baldwin (2006, p. 22) argues that it could continue to play a role in the proliferation of BTAs in the region in the coming years: “If history is any guide, the domino effect in East Asia will spread to many, many more countries in the neighborhood. In Europe, for example, the playing out of several waves of domino effects has left the EU with preferential trade deals with every WTO members except nine. It is therefore conceivable that the 13 members of the ASEAN+3 group will end up signing a very large number of bilaterals in the coming years.”

BTAs also tend to attract less attention all around, including from the media. So, the pressure from opposition forces at home- such as the anti-free trade lobby or particular “sensitive” industry groups- or from abroad- such as traditional trade partners or members of a regional grouping that the country is a part of, is likely to be low. This would facilitate not only the speed at which a BTA can be negotiated, but also the number of them. Of course there are exceptions, and these generally arise when the partner is a large country (eg. the US) or when sensitive sectors are involved in the negotiations of the BTA.

Finally, it is often claimed that some, if at most, BTAs are essentially politically motivated. There is no doubt that political economy considerations, and indeed political parties or politicians themselves, play a major role in driving the proliferation of BTAs. A recent example of this is how the control of both Houses by the Democrats has put at risk a number of the BTAs that the Bush administration has been pursuing. Although we try and take into account political, strategic and foreign policy related issues, we focus on economic and economic related considerations because they are easier to identify and measure. Thus, the discussion that follows is likely to understate the role that politics and politicians play in the proliferation of BTAs, simply because these influences are often difficult to measure or model, let alone classify.

 3.2 Specific Factors

There are three broad categories of specific factors that we identify: economic; strategic and event driven. As depicted in Figure 2, each of these broad categories have their sub-categories, and the sub-categories for economic and event driven BTAs are each sub-divided into two sub-categories as well. Thus, in total, we identify 11 specific factors to explain the proliferation of BTAs.

Figure 2.
The Different Motivations for Forming BTAs: Specific Factors

 3.2.1 Economically Motivated BTAs

Within the economic motivation, the two sub-categories are sector driven and market access BTAs. Sector driven BTAs are further sub-divided into sector excluding and sector expanding BTAs. Market access BTAs are also divided into two groups: market restoring and market creating.

Sector Driven BTAs
These BTAs are motivated mainly by one or a few key sectors. There is both a positive and negative element to this sector based motivation, with some BTAs designed to expand liberalization into sectors or areas that have previously been ignored at the multilateral level while others exclude sensitive sectors or issues. We discuss them separately because their impact on the world trading system is likely to be quite different depending on whether they are sector expanding or excluding

Sector Expanding BTAs
It is easy to see why BTAs are easier to negotiate and conclude than PTAs or a multilateral deal: with only two parties involved, the potential for disagreement is reduced. As the focus of liberalization shifts away from the relatively easier task of reducing trade taxes on industrial products, achieving agreement on a multilateral level has become more difficult as the agenda broadens to address less transparent forms of protection, more complex issues, and new sectors. By requiring only two parties to agree, a BTA could face fewer obstacles than a regional or multilateral pact. BTAs may then have the potential to achieve a deeper level of integration than that possible through the multilateral approach alone. Even if it is not any deeper, it is often argued that we might be able to get there more quickly using the bilateral approach compared to the multilateral one.

In other words, both the degree and scope of liberalization policy may be enhanced in the context of only two negotiating partners, and so bilateral efforts may be able to surpass the extent of integration possible at the multilateral level. In this sense, sector expanding BTAs are often described as ‘WTO Plus’ or ‘New Age’ BTAs. The US-Singapore BTA is one of the first such BTAs and is often described as a model worthy of emulation by other negotiating partners. In fact, the BTAs being pursued by the US with the other ASEAN countries as part of its “Enterprise for ASEAN Initiative” is using it as a model.

Of the various so-called “Singapore issues” that were raised at the WTO Ministerial Conference in Singapore in 1996, only the rather fuzzy concept of trade facilitation measures appears to have survived on the WTO agenda. Other Singapore issues such as establishing rules for investment, competition policy, and government procurement are being pursued in some sector expanding BTAs. Progress with liberalization of services in general has been slow at the multilateral level and fraught with difficulties given country-specific sensitivities. A wide-ranging multilateral deal looks unlikely in the near future. Some sector specific BTAs have emerged in response to such an environment. In this environment, BTAs have also been driven by the fact that preferential access may enable a supplier to steal an irreversible march on the competition, and cement a long-term advantage in the market. Many of the US BTAs with developing countries are pursuing more favorable rules relating to investment and intellectual property rights

Sector Excluding BTAs

The most sensitive sector as far as liberalization is concerned is agriculture. Most sector excluding BTAs relate, in one way or the other, to this sector. An example of the negative element would be the BTA between Japan and Singapore, known as the Japan-Singapore Economic Partnership Agreement (JSEPA). Japan has long resisted joining PTAs because of its reluctance to liberalize its agriculture sector, but the absence of any significant agricultural sector in the city state of Singapore has facilitated the signing of this BTA. Even the few agricultural products that Singapore does export were easily excluded from the JSEPA, such as cut flowers and ornamental fish. Less than 10 percent of the volume of exports of agricultural products from Singapore to Japan is provided with duty-free access, and the JSEPA did not create any new preferences in the agricultural sector (Ravenhill 2006).

A similar set of exclusions of sensitive sectors can be found in Japan’s BTA with Mexico. Unlike Singapore, Mexico does have a large agricultural sector and is a major exporter of meat (pork in particular) to Japan, so the exclusions have been so widespread that about 13 percent of Mexico’s exports to Japan are excluded from the BTA. So, even when agriculture is important to one partner but sensitive in the other, it appears that BTAs can still be concluded by excluding this sector. Clearly the flexibility provided by BTAs through one-on-one negotiations allow such compromises to be made and trade agreements to be concluded when they might otherwise stall or fail.

Market Access BTAs

As mentioned earlier, we divide market access BTAs into two groups: market restoring and market creating.

Market Restoring BTAs

In the discussion earlier on general factors behind the popularity of BTAs, we noted that one of the reasons was the apparent disenchantment with pace of progress with liberalization at the multilateral level. The same disenchantment with the WTO was one of many factors driving the original interest in PTAs of course. It also set off a kind of snowballing or domino effect (see Baldwin 1996). As the world trading system started being carved up into blocks, countries that did not belong to a PTA felt compelled to form or join one in order to secure regional markets, or compensate for markets in other regions that were becoming more isolated and less accessible as a result of preferential arrangements.

Some BTAs have developed in response to such a global trading environment. The motivation behind them is to try and restore trading links that existed prior to a trading partner joining a PTA. They generally apply to non-regional but traditional trade partners where one or both have become members of a relatively integrated PTA, which has weakened trade links between them as a result. These BTAs are designed to bypass, or at least reduce, the discriminatory treatment imposed upon them as a result of the PTA. Lloyd (2002, p. 6) describes this as the one factor that is common to all new PTAs and sees it as becoming more important relative to the other factors. As he puts it (pg. 6), “This is the fear of exclusion from major markets. In this context, exclusion does not mean that a country is denied access to a market, that is, total exclusion. It means that it has access on terms less favorable than some other country or countries”.

With the EU and NAFTA as centers of regional preferential trading, and with little or no prospect of other countries becoming members of these regional trading blocs, many of the BTAs being pursued with them (either with the EU or NAFTA or with individual member countries) would serve as examples of restoring market access BTAs.

The US is a major trading partner for most of the ASEAN countries. As noted earlier, with the exception of Myanmar, all other ASEAN countries have either concluded or are pursuing BTAs with the US. For the ASEAN countries, the BTAs are viewed as a means of restoring market access in the post-NAFTA era.

Market Creating BTAs

Market Creating BTAs usually involve countries seeking to strengthen trade and investment relations when there has been little or weak economic relations in the past. To the extent that limited trade in the past has been due to trade barriers or other regulatory or commercial restrictions, market creating BTAs may be successful in achieving its objective of promoting bilateral trade. For instance, it could be that both countries had relatively high trade barriers with the rest of the world, but then each removed them preferentially amongst regional partners in a PTA. In this case, there may be potential for boosting trade between the two countries through a BTA that opens-up a conduit between the PTAs that each country is a member of.

If, however, historically weak trade relations is due to economic reasons based on comparative advantage, such as competitive rather than complementary resource endowments, then such BTAs will have little, if any, effect on boosting bilateral trade, unless the preference margins are very large.

 3.2.2 Strategically Motivated BTAs

BTAs that are motivated by strategic factors are classified into two groups: lobby driven and terror driven. Each is discussed in turn below.

Lobby Driven BTAs
The Seattle Ministerial Meeting of the WTO collapsed in the face of developing countries opposing the push by a number of developed countries, spearheaded by the US and the EU, to introduce labor standards and environmental regulations on to the WTO agenda. Having failed at the WTO, critics claim that the US is now trying to press ahead with this agenda by intimidating small, weak countries into accepting them in one-on-one negotiations, while simultaneously trying to seduce them with preferential access to a large domestic market. The so-called “fair trade” push by the US and the EU is seen as nothing less than covert protectionism that penalizes exports from low wage emerging and developing economies. Bhagwati (2005) also laments the introduction of what he describes as trade-unrelated "fair trade" demands, referring not only to labor and environmental standards but also intellectual property rights protection, on to the agenda of a trade organization.

The first precedent relating to labor standards was set in NAFTA, or more specifically by the North American Agreement on Labor Cooperation (NAALC), which was negotiated as a side agreement to NAFTA, which came into effect on 1 January, 1994. But critics such as Bhagwati (2005) complain of a ratcheting up effect, as these issues progress from being annexes to trade agreements and into their text. With the US-Jordan BTA, labor standards and environmental regulations found their way into the body of the agreement for the first time. With the BTAs with Chile and Singapore, the agenda broadened to include capital controls, and these agreements forbid these countries from using them. The precedent setting formula is described as a blueprint pattern, whereby the “strongest” BTA to date serves as a model for negotiating the next one.

Terror Driven BTAs

It would appear that US trade policy has not escaped the Bush Administration’s apparent preoccupation with fighting the ‘war on terror’. Some of the US’s BTAs are viewed as another instrument in pursuing this objective. As Tonelson (2002) notes, “trade policy as an anti-terror weapon is an understandably appealing idea. It doesn’t put American soldiers in harm’s way. It is non-violent, market-friendly and holds the promise of ‘draining the swamp’ where terrorists are assumed to thrive. And it doesn’t require a line in the federal budget.” The use of trade incentives has long been a part of US foreign policy. During the Cold War in particular, trade and access to the US market was used to strengthen ties with allies such as Taipei,China, South Korea, and Israel (with whom the US signed its first BTA in 1985).

There is an element of rewarding friends and forging new geopolitical links by engaging potential foes in this current pursuit. The TIFA with Pakistan and subsequent strong push to conclude a BTA is an example of rewarding an ally for continuing support in this endeavor. The Middle East Free Trade Initiative, proposed by President Bush in May 2003, has already seen BTAs concluded with Jordan, Morocco, and Bahrain, and negotiations are on-going with Oman and the United Arab Emirates. According to FTA Watch (2006), the BTA with Morocco is designed “to ’reward’ a moderate Muslim government for its support to the White House’s ’war on terror’ and to pull a friendly North African kingdom deeper into its sphere of influence, creating a wedge vis-à-vis the Arab world”. The US strategy in the Middle East is a graduated one, negotiating bilateral trade agreements country by country before moving toward a regional agreement to be completed in 2013. Strong supporters of the war on Iraq, such as Australia, are also in negotiations with the US on a BTA which would reward Australian firms with the opportunity to directly tender, for the first time, for US government contracts.

 3.2.3 Event Driven BTAs

Event driven BTAs are divided into three sub-categories: PTA, WTO and Political. The PTA sub-category is further divided into PTA facilitation and PTA integration BTAs, while political BTAs are divided into political integration and political disintegration BTAs.

PTA Facilitation BTAs

These are BTAs that are designed to hasten the pace of integration between a country seeking to join a PTA of which the other country is a member. In other words, it is a BTA between a non-member and a member of a BTA. Although both parties are usually countries, they need not be so; they could also be BTAs or PTAs. An example of this would be the India-Thailand BTA, with India looking to strengthen ties with AFTA. The same is true of the “Plus 3” countries of ASEAN, with the PRC, Japan and Korea pursuing individual BTAs with ASEAN members. Such BTAs can also be pursued with the PTA as a whole, and all the “Plus 3” countries are doing so with ASEAN.

PTA Integration BTAs

These are BTAs between members of a PTA. These types of BTAs stand out because unlike all other BTAs, the parties involved already have some form of a preferential trade agreement designed to promote closer economic relations between them. Examples of such BTAs include the Lao PDR-Viet Nam BTA and the Singapore-Thailand BTA, where all countries are also members of AFTA.

WTO Accession BTAs

These BTAs are essentially a means to an end, and that end is WTO accession. Countries wanting to join the WTO have to negotiate bilateral agreements with major economic powers (such as the US and EU) as part of their entry procedure. These bilateral negotiations lead to specific commitments, concessions and schedules to liberalize trade in goods and services. The results of these bilateral negotiations are merged with the results of more general negotiations carried out between the candidate country and a working party of the WTO membership to form an overall "accession package".

For non-members, the WTO would appear as the largest and most restrictive PTA in the world. With 149 member countries, it is the most restrictive because the cumulative domestic content requirement to access WTO accords is effectively 100 percent. In this way. WTO accession BTAs have much in common with PTA facilitation BTAs from the perspective of non-members. Almost all (28 out of 33) observers to the WTO are currently negotiating facilitating bilateral WTO accession agreements, mostly with the US. For instance, the largest non-member of the WTO, Russia, will sign a BTA with the US during the 2006 APEC Summit in Hanoi, and this is expected to finally clear the way for its accession. Prior to 2002, almost half of the country-to-country BTAs notified to the WTO involved at least one non-member of the WTO.
Political Integration BTAs
Political Integration BTAs are designed to hasten the economic integration of recent political unions. Examples of these include the BTAs between PRC and its two Special Administrative Regions (SARs), Hong Kong, China (the first BTA for both parties), and Macao, China. As noted earlier, these entities are members of the WTO in their own right but have since become SARs of the PRC. It is also interesting that Hong Kong, China’s Chief Executive, Tung Chee Hwa, approached Beijing with the BTA proposal only days after the PRC announced that the SARs would not be included in the proposed PRC-ASEAN FTA (see Dent 2006).

Taipei,China is also a member of the WTO but has so far rejected PRC’s offer of becoming a SAR. It does not have a BTA with the PRC nor is it pursuing one. Instead, it is actively pursuing a BTA with the US, which appears unlikely to be concluded as a result of political pressure from the PRC, and apparent concern by the US over its poor record in protecting Intellectual property rights. In the absence of such a BTA, and in order to gain access to the US market, Taipei,China is pursuing BTAs with as many of the Central American countries as it can. This is seen as a way of pursuing access to the US market through the backdoor.

Political Disintegration BTAs

The break up of the Soviet Union in 1991 resulted in 15 newly independent or post-Soviet States. Following this political disintegration, these newly independent states have been rapidly forging BTAs between each other. In fact, it appears as if BTAs will be signed between most, if not all, of these countries. These BTAs appear to work to restore some degree of political affiliation while ensuring continued economic integration despite political dissolution. They can work as an interim measure to secure market access for goods when market institutions, payments arrangements, and exchange rate convertibility are not yet fully functioning (Tumbarello1 2005). The strengthening of ties amongst each other may also be designed to counter the influence of Russia in the region, and in this way further strengthen their independence. Being newly independent states, many are also not yet members of the WTO. Forging alliances through BTAs or a PTA could strengthen their collective bargaining power and consolidate common positions in negotiating the most favourable deal in WTO accession.

4. Impact on Multilateralism and the World Trading System

We began Section 3 by examining a number of general factors that were driving the proliferation of BTAs. We begin this Section by examining the general impact that the overall growth in the number of BTAs is having on multilateralism and the world trading system, before turning to the effects that different types of BTAs are having.

 4.1 Impact of General Factors

A general concern relating to the explosion of BTAs is the distractive effect it is having on multilateralism. As countries devote more and more of their resources towards discussing, designing, negotiating and implementing BTAs, less are available to be directed towards multilateralism. This would be particularly true for the smaller and poorer developing countries, where such resources are particularly scarce. Apart from detracting from the multilateral effort, interest in unilateral trade liberalization, an important but often overlooked modality in the overall liberalization effort of the past few decades, is also likely to wane in the light of the obsession with BTAs.

A related concern is that the appeal of reviving the stalled Doha round of the WTO will fade as more and more BTAs are negotiated. To the extent that BTAs are being pursued to compensate for the perceived inadequacies, or subsequent collapse, of the Doha round, the apparent need to revive it will presumably diminish with each successive BTA. But can BTAs, if there are enough of them, substitute for a multilateral deal? In other words, does a BTA with every member of the WTO sum to equal a multilateral deal, for instance? Although this could be true in theory, it is unlikely to be so in practice, for at least two reasons: (i) the products covered in each BTA are unlikely to be the same; i.e., the set of exclusions are likely to vary depending on the partner country; and (ii) the assortment of implementing rules are likely to vary across BTAs. This being the case, the sheer number of BTAs cannot substitute for a multilateral deal and, to the extent that it reduces the likelihood of reaching such a deal, it is detrimental to the world trading system.

The fact that most BTAs and PTAs are WTO-consistent does not do much to allay concerns relating to their potentially detrimental effects on the world trading system either. This is because the requirements of Article XXIV and the Enabling Clause and the General Agreement on Trade and Services (GATS) are very weak and have never really been enforced. For instance, as Lloyd (2002) points out, the meaning of “substantially all trade” has never been defined and has been interpreted in many ways. The only effective restraint that GATT/WTO rules have imposed on BTAs and PTAs is that they have generally prevented trade barriers from being raised against third countries. Furthermore, almost all of the deep integration features of recent BTAs are altogether outside the WTO rules.

 4.2 Impact of Specific Factors

 4.2.1 Impact of Economically Motivated BTAs

Sector Expanding BTAs

Whether sector expanding BTAs can support multilateralism will depend on whether the accords, which apparently can be achieved at the bilateral but not multilateral level, are eventually offered on a multilateral MFN basis to non-members. So far, there is limited evidence of this happening, but then it might still be too soon to pass judgment.

There is also concern that if the major trading nations achieve liberalization in new sectors through bilateral or plurilateral agreements amongst each other, then the perceived returns from, or motivation for, a WTO-wide agreement will diminish. A WTO agreement would allow smaller, developing countries to free-ride on achievements made at the multilateral level. Without such a deal, and with limited multilateralization of BTA accords, the smaller, developing countries may be locked out and will not be able to participate in the benefits of liberalized markets.

Sometimes BTAs can set positive precedents and develop negotiation modalities that can be adopted later in multilateral negotiations. The Canada-US FTA is an example of this. This BTA developed concepts and modalities in the service trade area that was important in the development of GATS. This can serve the objectives of multilateralism by advancing the agenda in a demonstrably attainable way.

Sector Excluding BTAs

Although sector excluding BTAs may provide a vehicle to overcome obstacles preventing progress with liberalization in other areas, are they working to further compromise liberalization of these sectors at the multilateral level? It would seem that they are. Basically, they set a negative precedent that can be exploited. Once a country succeeds in securing exclusion, it can use the precedent set in negotiations with other countries. For example, once Japan was able to secure exclusions for certain agricultural products in the JSEPA with Singapore, the same exclusions were insisted upon in negotiations with Mexico and Korea. But other countries can also refer to these precedents in their own negotiations. Korea, for instance, was reported to have cited the Japanese exclusions in agriculture to strengthen its negotiating position in pressing for the same with Mexico (Min 2006).

The multilateral approach is arguably the best forum to deal with liberalization of these excluded sectors because it has one key advantage over the bilateral (or regional) approach in this respect. This is the ability to trade concessions across disparate interests; that is, to weigh up the costs to countries of conceding protection in sensitive sectors (such as agriculture) against the benefits from increased market access in areas in which they have a comparative advantage (eg. through changes to rules relating to investment, intellectual property or services). Every time a BTA allows a country to bypass this trade-off simply through its choice of partner, and secure benefits without incurring costs, the task of liberalizing such sensitive sectors is made more difficult.

Market Restoring BTAs

As members of a PTA engage in more and more BTAs with non-members, the PTA becomes more porous. In this way, BTAs can work to reduce the restrictiveness of existing trading blocs, and open them up to external trade, albeit in a somewhat piece-meal fashion. If a high share of members of a PTA engage in a large number BTAs with non-members, then this has the potential to return trading patterns to a form that existed prior to the establishment of the PTA. In this way, such BTAs have the potential to dilute preference margins and thereby reduce the trade diversion induced by the PTA. If they do this, then Market Restoring BTAs would complement the multilateral trading system and work as building rather than stumbling blocks towards free and open trade.

Market Creating BTAs

The impact of Market Creating BTA on multilateralism and the world trading system depends on the type of trade that it generates. If the preferences provided by the BTA serve to divert trade that was previously being conducted with a country that was a lower-cost supplier, then this would be welfare-reducing. If, on the other hand, the BTA works to reduce or remove trade barriers or other restrictions that have previously constrained bilateral trade between the two countries, then the impact on multilateralism could be positive, even if second-best. Thus, a lot depends on why trade relations had been limited to begin with. If historically weak trade relations are due to resource endowments being competitive rather than complementary, then such BTAs, if they affect trade patters, will run counter to multilateralism. Even if they do not affect trade patters, their impact may still be negative because administering the BTA and implementing the rules associated with it will still be a drain on resources.

 4.2.2 Impact of Strategically Motivated BTAs

Lobby Driven and Terror Driven BTAs
We discuss the impact that lobby driven and terror driven BTAs are likely to have on multilateralism jointly because they both involve the use of trade policy to pursue non-trade related objectives.

To the extent that BTAs, a trade policy instrument, are used to pursue non-trade related objectives, the likelihood that the BTA is distorting is increased. If terror driven BTAs are designed to reward allies for instance, it cannot do so unless it provides a margin of preference sufficiently high to divert a significant amount of trade. In fact, it may de designed to do so, if the objective is to reward, in a one-sided transfer, rather than to be mutually beneficial, from a gains from trade point of view.

The main concern relating to lobby driven BTAs is that they may be setting precedents that run counter to multilateral principles, and may be promoting protectionism.

Furthermore, as Lloyd (2002) points out, it is useful to adopt a global welfare point of view in evaluating such BTAs, and ask if they have a positive effect on world welfare. For lobby driven BTAs in particular, this approach also avoids having to make value judgments associated with the objectives being pursued and focuses attention on economic effects. Prima facie, both lobby driven and terror driven BTAs appear unlikely to raise global welfare for at least two reasons. First, the fact such BTAs are likely to be trade distorting suggest that global welfare will be reduced as a result. This negative welfare impact may be higher for terror driven BTAs because they may be trade diverting by design, where as lobby driven BTAs are trade distorting only as a consequence of using the wrong instrument to pursue a particular objective. Second, as various empirical studies have shown, BTAs and PTAs generally result in the welfare of some non-members being reduced, and the extent of the welfare reduction is usually related to the extent of which trade is distorted. For highly-distorting BTAs, the extent of the global reduction in welfare is also likely to be high.

Apart from the effect on global welfare and the world trading system, others such as Bhagwati (2003) are also concerned about the impact that lobby driven BTAs are having on the WTO as an institution. The concern is that the WTO, a trade institution, is being turned into an institution where domestic lobbies, whether good or bad, can park their agendas and capture, and distort, the working of the institution itself.

 4.2.3 Impact of Event Driven BTAs

PTA Facilitation BTAs

Whether or not PTA facilitation BTAs serve the interests of multilateralism depends on the PTA concerned. If the PTA is inward-looking, has complex rules of origin requirements and a high margin of preference, the BTA may hinder multilateralism and hamper the world trading system. If the PTA, on the other hand, is based on open regionalism, the BTA may assist the non-PTA member to hasten its liberalization and integration with the world trading system.

PTA Integration BTAs

A BTA between these countries suggests that, prima facie, they wish to pursue a level of integration that surpasses that possible with the PTA that they are members of. Often members of a PTA can only proceed as fast as its slowest or least ambitious member, especially if the decision making process is consensus based. A BTA may then allow some of its members to pursue more ambitious liberalization programs. This should lead to a positive outcome for the world trading system if it results in a deeper level of integration.

WTO Accession BTAs

By supporting the process of WTO accession, these BTAs serve to promote multilateralism. Sometimes, the bilateral agreements commit countries to rules on trade liberalization that exceed those of the WTO. For instance, Ecuador had to renounce its status as a "developing country", based on demands from the US, and thereby implement several WTO agreements within a much shorter timeframe. The PRC agreed to a range of "WTO-plus" measures pushed separately by the US and the EU, including anti-dumping measures and import restrictions to curtail the entry of Chinese goods into their markets, prior to WTO accession.
Conclusions and the Future Landscape of World Trade
The interest in forming BTAs has been growing at a phenomenal rate. In the Asia-Pacific region alone, the number of BTAs has more than tripled over the past 5 years, from 57 in 2002 to 176 in October 2006. Furthermore, this interest seems to be increasing at an increasing rate! The key distinguishing feature of bilateralism is the amount of flexibility it provides- both in terms of process and in pursuing disparate interests. Any two countries, in any part of the world, can form a BTA simply by wanting to do so. In a one-on-one setting, just about any objective can be pursued, and trade-offs can be designed to accommodate parties concerned in a way that would be difficult to do in a plurilateral or multilateral setting.

In this context, it is not surprising that a wide array of both economic and non-economic factors appear to be driving the proliferation of BTAs. We identified a set of general and specific factors involved. The general factors were: disenchantment with progress of the WTO; snowballing and domino effects as a result of countries not wanting to be left behind; lower visibility and thus lower resistance from opposing forces; and pure politics driven by politicians and political parties. There are three broad categories of specific factors that we identify: economic; strategic and event driven. Each of these broad categories have their sub-categories, and the sub-categories for economic and event driven BTAs are each sub-divided into two sub-categories as well. Thus, in total, we identified 11 specific factors to explain the proliferation of BTAs.

In general, it is would appear that the sheer number of BTAs and their continued rapid growth is fragmenting the world trading system. The most obvious effect is the much discussed spaghetti-bowl effect. It is also distracting, and drawing scarce resources away from the multilateral effort. But the story is not that simple or straight-forward once we consider specific factors. The fallacy of division applies because the motivation in pursuing a BTA can determine if its impact on the world trading system is positive or negative. Whether or not a BTA contributes to the integration or fragmentation of the world trading system can vary depending on this.

Most of the event driven BTAs, except perhaps some PTA facilitation BTAs, appear to either support multilateralism or have a positive effect on the world trading system. All of the strategically motivated BTAs appear to have a negative effect. Of the economically motivated BTAs, sector expanding and market restoring BTAs have the potential of supporting the multilateral process, while market creating and sector excluding BTAs appear to threaten it.

Are BTAs likely to continue proliferating? At the moment, the answer appears to be yes, since they are increasing at an increasing rate. How much longer is this likely to continue, and where is all of this likely to lead? One view is that they will continue to proliferate until the world trading system is so distorted that countries will be forced to seek a remedy. This response may take several forms.

One is the consolidation of BTAs into region-wide PTAs, or blocks, where the various BTAs between members belonging to the same region become largely redundant. For instance, many if not all of the event driven BTAs are likely to fall into this category, but there could be more. There are numerous examples of defunct BTAs following the establishment of the EU. In the Asia-Pacific region, the US-Canada BTA was superseded by the establishment of NAFTA, and the India-Sri Lanka BTA by SAFTA. An Asia-wide FTA would supersede a host of regional BTAs, and consolidate them into one region-wide agreement.

Although this may reduce the number of intra-regional BTAs, it may be somewhat of a hollow victory if it serves to further fragment the world trading system by carving it up into distinct regional blocks. Furthermore, it may provide fresh impetus for a new wave of market restoring BTAs as traditional trade partners outside the region seek to retain trade access with members of the consolidated PTA. In fact, with more countries outside the region that inside, it is possible that the total number of BTAs could increase if the reduction in the number of intra-regional BTAs through a consolidated PTA is more than offset by the number of inter-regional market restoring BTAs that it indirectly induces. This is hardly a remedy to the problems facing the world trading system.

The second response may come in the form of the completion of the Doha round with minimum compromises. This would undoubtedly be the preferred response to the current chaotic environment of criss-crossing BTAs. A bona fide conclusion to the Doha Round should dilute preferences that are currently scattered around the world, and take away much of the incentive to continue pursuing BTAs. If this happens, then the proliferation of BTAs would have contributed to their eventual demise, in terms of their impact on the world trading system. This is much more like a remedy to the problems facing the world trading system.

But what is the Doha round fails, or is concluded in such a watered-down and compromised form that its impact is minimal? Although this may provide an additional incentive to pursue more BTAs and PTAs, there may eventually come a point where countries may voluntarily seek a remedy that lies in their own best interests. One thing that is clear is that the cost of administering and implementing multiple country-specific BTAs is costly. The cost to the supplying countries also rises with the number of country-specific BTAs. The cost of applying for preferences is also apparently high, and may explain why only a very small percentage of non-agricultural world trade is conducted under preferential terms (see Grether and Olarreaga 1998).

Once a country has concluded BTAs with most, if not all, of its major trading partners, it may then make sense to: equalize preferences across these BTAs and then offer them to non-BTA countries on an MFN basis. This would remove the administrative burden, and eliminate distortions to country and global trade patterns. As it is with reversing much of second-best policies, it is the actual realized cost of implementation rather than any potential unrealized benefits that actually drives the process. And there are significant potential unrealized benefits that will accrue to the country concerned as well as the world trading system if this process of multilateralizing preferences is pursued, whatever the reason.

References

Baldwin, Richard E. (1996), “A Domino Theory of Regionalism” in Richard E. Baldwin, P. Haaparanta and J. Kiander (eds.), Expanding Membership of the EU, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Baldwin, Richard E. (2006), "Managing the Noodle Bowl: The Fragility of East Asian Regionalism", CEPR Discussion Paper No. 5561, London: CEPR.

Bhagwati, Jagdish N. (1995), “Trade Liberalization and Fair Trade Demands: Addressing the Environmental and Labour Standards Issues”, World Economy 18, 745-59.

Bhagwati, Jagdish N. (2003) “The Singapore and Chile Free Trade Agreements”, Testimony before U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Financial Services, April 1, 2003.

Bhagwati, Jagdish N. (2005) “From Seattle to Hong Kong”, Foreign Affairs 84/7, December (WTO Special Edition).

Brittan, S. (2005), “Free Trade versus ‘Fair Trade’ Remarks at Foreign Policy Centre meeting with Hilary Benn 10/01/05. Downloadable from <http://www.samuelbrittan.co.uk/spee...>

Dent, Christopher (2006) New Free Trade Agreements in the Asia Pacific, Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan.

Feridhanusetyawan, Tubagus, (2005) “Preferential Trading Agreements in the Asia-Pacific Region”, IMF Working Paper 149, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

FTA Watch (2006) “Overview of Bilateral Free Trade and Investment Agreements”, Background paper prepared for the Fighting FTAs workshop, Bangkok, 27-29 July.

Grether, Jean-Marie and Marcelo Olarreaga (1998), “Preferential and Non-preferential Trade Flows in World Trade, Staff Working Paper ERAD-98-10, Geneva: WTO.

Lloyd, Peter (2002), New Regionalism and New Bilateralism in the Asia-Pacific, Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.

Looney, Robert E. (2005), "US Middle East Economic Policy: The Use of Free Trade Areas in the War on Terrorism", Mediterranean Quarterly 16(3), pp. 102-117.

Menon, Jayant, (1996), Adjusting towards AFTA: The Dynamics of Trade in ASEAN. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.

Menon, Jayant (2000) “The Evolving ASEAN Free Trade Area: Widening and Deepening”, Asian Development Review 18(1): 49-72.

Menon, Jayant (2005) “Building Blocks or Stumbling Blocks: Regional Cooperation Arrangements in Southeast Asia, Discussion Paper No. 41, Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.

Min Gyo Koo (2006) ‘From Multilateralism to Bilateralism. A Shift in South Korea’s Trade Strategy?”, in Vinod K. Agrawal and Shujiro Urata (eds.), Bilateral Trade Agreements in the Asia-Pacific¸ London: Routledge, 140-59.

Panagariya, A. (1999), “The Regionalism Debate: An Overview”, World Economy 22, 477-511.

Ravenhill, John (2006), “The Political Economy of the New Asia-Pacific Bilateralism: Benign, Banal, or Simply Bad?”, in Vinod K. Agrawal and Shujiro Urata (eds.), Bilateral trade Agreements in the Asia-Pacific¸ London: Routledge, 27-49.

Scollay, R. and J. P. Gilbert (2001), New Regional Trading Arrangements in the Asia Pacific?,
Institute for International Economics, Washington, D. C.

Tumbarello, Patrizia (2005), “Regional Trade Integration and WTO Accession: Which Is the Right Sequencing? An Application to the CIS”, IMF Working Paper WP/05/94, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

Tonelson, Alan (2002), “There’s Only So Much That Foreign Trade Can Do,” The Washington Post, June 2.

Wonnacott, R. J. (1996), “Trade and Investment in a Hub-and-spoke System versus a Free Trade Area”, World Economy 19(3), 237-252.

Table 1
BTAs of Countries in the Asia-Pacific Region, and Status (up to October 2006)

No. Bilateral Trade Agreement Status
1 Armenia-Georgia Free Trade Area Under Implementation
2 Armenia-Kazakhstan Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
3 Armenia-Kyrgyz Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
4 Armenia-Moldova Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
5 Armenia-Russian Federation Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
6 Armenia-Turkmenistan Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
7 Armenia-Ukraine Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
8 ASEAN-Australia and New Zealand Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
9 ASEAN-China Free Trade Area Under Implementation
10 ASEAN-EU Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
11 ASEAN-India Regional Trade and Investment Area (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
12 ASEAN-Japan Comprehensive Economic Partnership (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
13 ASEAN-Korea Free Trade Area Signed
14 Australia-Japan Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
15 Australia-Mexico Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
16 Australia-New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement Under Implementation
17 Australia-United Arab Emirates Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
18 Azerbaijan-Georgia Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
19 Azerbaijan-Kazakhstan Free Trade Agreement Signed
20 Azerbaijan-Moldova Free Trade Agreement Signed
21 Azerbaijan-Russia Free Trade Agreement Signed
22 Azerbaijan-Turkmenistan Free Trade Agreement Signed
23 Azerbaijan-Ukraine Free Trade Agreement Signed
24 Azerbaijan-Uzbekistan Free Trade Agreement Signed
25 Canada-Chile Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
26 Canada-Costa Rica Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
27 Canada-Dominican Republic Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
28 Canada-Israel Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
29 Canada-Singapore Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
30 Canada-United States Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
31 China-India Regional Trading Arrangement Proposed/Under consultation and study
32 EFTA-Singapore Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
33 India-Afghanistan Preferential Trading Agreement Signed
34 India-Australia Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
35 India-Chile Preferential Trading Agreement Signed
36 India-Colombia Preferential Trading Arrangement Proposed/Under consultation and study
37 India-Egypt Preferential Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
38 India-European Union Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
39 India-Gulf Cooperation Council Free Trade Area (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
40 India-Indonesia Comprehensive Economic Cooperation Arrangement Proposed/Under consultation and study
41 India-Israel Preferential Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
42 India-Korea Comprehensive Economic Partnership Agreement Under Negotiation
43 India-Mauritius Comprehensive Economic Cooperation and Partnership Agreement Under Negotiation
44 India-MERCOSUR Preferential Trade Agreement Signed
45 India-Singapore Comprehensive Economic Cooperation Agreement Under Implementation
46 India-Southern African Customs Union Preferential Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
47 India-Sri Lanka Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
48 India-Thailand Free Trade Area (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
49 India-Uruguay Preferential Trading Arrangement Proposed/Under consultation and study
50 India-Venezuela Preferential Trading Arrangement Proposed/Under consultation and study
51 Indo-Nepal Treaty of Trade Under Implementation
52 Japan-Brunei Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
53 Japan-Canada Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
54 Japan-Chile Economic Partnership Agreement Under Negotiation
55 Japan-Gulf Cooperation Council Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
56 Japan-India Economic Partnership Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
57 Japan-Indonesia Economic Partnership Agreement Under Negotiation
58 Japan-Korea Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
59 Japan-Malaysia Economic Partnership Agreement Under Implementation
60 Japan-Mexico Economic Partnership Agreement Under Implementation
61 Japan-Philippines Economic Partnership Agreement Signed
62 Japan-Singapore Economic Agreement for a New-Age Partnership Under Implementation
63 Japan-Switzerland Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
64 Japan-Thailand Economic Partnership Agreement Under Negotiation
65 Japan-Vietnam Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
66 Kazakhstan-Georgia Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
67 Korea-Canada Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
68 Korea-Chile Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
69 Korea-European Free Trade Association Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
70 Korea-MERCOSUR Preferential Trading Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
71 Korea-Mexico Strategic Economic Complementation Agreement Under Negotiation
72 Korea-Singapore Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
73 Korea-South Africa Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
74 Korea-United States Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
75 Kyrgyz-Kazakhstan Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
76 Kyrgyz-Moldova Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
77 Kyrgyz-Russia Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
78 Kyrgyz-Ukraine Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
79 Kyrgyz-Uzbekistan Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
80 Laos-Thailand Preferential Trading Arrangement Under Implementation
81 Malaysia-Australia Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
82 Malaysia-Chile Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
83 Malaysia-India Comprehensive Economic Cooperation Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
84 Malaysia-Korea Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
85 Malaysia-New Zealand Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
86 Malaysia-Pakistan Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
87 New Zealand-China Free Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
88 New Zealand-Hong Kong Closer Economic Partnership Under Negotiation
89 New Zealand-Korea Closer Economic Partnership Proposed/Under consultation and study
90 New Zealand-Mexico Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
91 New Zealand-Singapore Closer Economic Partnership Under Implementation
92 Pacific ACP-EC Economic Partnership Agreement Under Negotiation
93 Pakistan-Afghanistan Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
94 Pakistan-Bangladesh Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
95 Pakistan-Gulf Cooperation Council Free Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
96 Pakistan-Indonesia Free Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
97 Pakistan-Iran Preferential Trade Agreement Signed
98 Pakistan-Jordan Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
99 Pakistan-Kazakhstan Preferential Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
100 Pakistan-Mauritius Preferential Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
101 Pakistan-MERCOSUR Preferential Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
102 Pakistan-Morocco Preferential Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
103 Pakistan-Philippines Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
104 Pakistan-Singapore Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
105 Pakistan-Sri Lanka Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
106 Pakistan-Tajikistan Preferential Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
107 Pakistan-Thailand Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
108 Pakistan-Turkey Preferential Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
109 Papua New Guinea-Australia Trade and Commercial Region Under Implementation
110 People’s Republic of China-Australia Free Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
111 People’s Republic of China-Chile Free Trade Agreement Signed
112 People’s Republic of China-Gulf Cooperation Council Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
113 People’s Republic of China-Hong Kong Closer Economic Partnership Arrangement Under Implementation
114 People’s Republic of China-Iceland Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
115 People’s Republic of China-Japan-Korea Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
116 People’s Republic of China-Korea Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
117 People’s Republic of China-Macao Closer Economic Partnership Arrangement Under Implementation
118 People’s Republic of China-Pakistan Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
119 People’s Republic of China-South Africa Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
120 People’s Republic of China-South African Customs Union Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
121 People’s Republic of China-Thailand Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
122 Singapore-Australia Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
123 Singapore-Bahrain Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
124 Singapore-Egypt Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
125 Singapore-Jordan Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
126 Singapore-Kuwait Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
127 Singapore-Mexico Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
128 Singapore-Panama Free Trade Agreement Signed
129 Singapore-Peru Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
130 Singapore-Qatar Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
131 Singapore-Sri Lanka Comprehensive Economic Partnership Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
132 Singapore-United Arab Emirates Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
133 Sri Lanka-Iran Preferential Trade Agreement Signed
134 Taipei,China and Dominican Republic Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
135 Taipei,China and El Salvador Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
136 Taipei,China and Guatemala Free Trade Agreement Signed
137 Taipei,China and Honduras Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
138 Taipei,China and Nicaragua Free Trade Agreement Signed
139 Taipei,China and Panama Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
140 Taipei,China and Paraguay Free Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
141 Tajikistan-Armenia Free Trade Agreement Signed
142 Tajikistan-Belarus Free Trade Agreement Signed
143 Tajikistan-Kyrgyz Free Trade Agreement Signed
144 Tajikistan-Russia Free Trade Agreement Signed
145 Tajikistan-Ukraine Free Trade Agreement Signed
146 Tajikistan-Uzbekistan Free Trade Agreement Signed
147 Thailand-Australia Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
148 Thailand-Bahrain Free Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
149 Thailand-Chile Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
150 Thailand-EFTA Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
151 Thailand-MERCOSUR Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
152 Thailand-New Zealand Closer Economic Partnership Agreement Under Implementation
153 Thailand-Peru Free Trade Agreement (FA) signed/FTA Under Negotiation
154 Turkmenistan-Georgia Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
155 United States-Australia Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
156 United States-Bahrain Free Trade Agreement Signed
157 United States-Brunei Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
158 United States-Chile Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
159 United States-Indonesia Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
160 United States-Israel Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
161 United States-Hashemite Kingdom of Jordan Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
162 United States-Malaysia Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
163 United States-Marshall Islands Compact of Free Association Under Implementation
164 United States-Micronesia Compact of Free Association Under Implementation
165 United States-Morocco Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
166 United States-Pakistan Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
167 United States-Palau Compact of Free Association Under Implementation
168 United States-Philippines Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
169 United States-Singapore Free Trade Agreement Under Implementation
170 United States-Sri Lanka Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
171 United States-Taipei,China Free Trade Agreement Proposed/Under consultation and study
172 United States-Thailand Free Trade Agreement Under Negotiation
173 Uzbekistan-Georgia Free Trade Agreement Signed
174 Uzbekistan-Kazakhstan Free Trade Agreement Signed
175 Uzbekistan-Moldova Free Trade Agreement Signed
176 Uzbekistan-Russia Free Trade Agreement Signed

Sources: Author’s compilation based on data from the following websites: ADB ARIC <aric.adb.org> ; Bilaterals.org <www.bilaterals.org>; ; Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada <www.dfait-maeci.gc.ca>; ; Office of the US Trade Representative <www.ustr.gov>; ; and WTO <www.wto.org>; .

Table 2
BTAs and PTAs of Asia-Pacific Countries, 1976-2006

YEAR BTAs PTAs
1976 0 1
1981 0 2
1983 1 2
1985 2 2
1989 3 2
1991 5 2
1992 6 2
1993 9 4
1994 12 5
1995 19 5
1996 27 5
1997 33 6
1998 37 6
1999 39 6
2000 41 6
2001 47 6
2002 57 6
2003 70 10
2004 109 13
2005 151 13
2006 176 17

Sources: Author’s compilation based on data from the following websites: ADB ARIC; Bilaterals.org; Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada; Office of the US Trade Representative; and WTO <www.wto.org>; .

Footnotes:

[*This is a revised version of a paper presented to the Joint ADBI-IDB LAEBA Seminar on Regional Integration and Regional Cooperation in Asia and Latin America on 14 November 2006 at the ADB Institute. I am grateful to Sisira Jayasuriya for valuable discussions. Any errors are mine. The views expressed herein reflect those of the author and should not be taken to reflect those of the Asian Development Bank Institute. Address comments or queries to the author at ADBI, Kasumigaseki Building 8F, 3-2-5 Kasumigaseki, Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo 100-6008; E-mail: jmenon@adbi.org


 source: