bilaterals.org logo
bilaterals.org logo
   

Trade agreements for the future, not the past

The Hankyoreh | 20 September 2006.

Trade Agreements for the Future, not the Past

By Dean Baker, Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research,

Politicians tend to be very backward looking people. They are usually the
last to notice important trends and to recognize the ways in which the world
is changing. Perhaps this is why many politicians in South Korea place such
a high priority on a new trade agreement with the United States. They insist
on looking backward to the past, rather than assessing what is likely to
happen in the future.

Looking backward, a trade deal with the United States would seem to be a top
economic priority. The size of the annual U.S. import market expanded by
more than US$1.1 trillion over the last decade. Any country would rightly
value more open access to such a rapidly growing market.

However, this is a backward looking story. The United States now has a
current account deficit of almost US$900 billion a year, primarily due to
the fact that it is importing much more than it is exporting. No economist
believes that the United States will be able to sustain a deficit of this
size for very long. At some point in the not very distant future, the
current account deficit will have to shrink, which means that imports will
have to fall. Instead of growing rapidly, the U.S. import market will be
shrinking rapidly. The Center for Economic and Policy Research put out a
report earlier this year that projected that the decline in the size of the
U.S. annual import market will be close to US$300 billion. This means that
South Korea is now negotiating to secure privileged access to a U.S. import
market that will implode in the near future.

The exact point at which the U.S. import market will begin to decline is
difficult to predict. This is due to the fact that market is currently being
sustained by the decision of foreign central banks (most importantly those
of China and Japan) to keep a high value of the dollar against their own
currencies, through buying up vast amounts of dollars on international money
markets. By keeping the value of the dollar high relative to their own
currencies, these central banks are keeping their countries’ exports to the
United States at low prices. In effect, these foreign central banks are
paying the United States to buy their own countries’ goods.

Subsidizing U.S. consumers to buy exports may be a good strategy for a
country that can find no other way of stimulating demand, but presumably
these central banks will eventually decide that they have paid enough money
to subsidize the consumption of the richest country in the world. There are
other policy tools to stimulate demand - for example, spending money on a
country’s infrastructure or its education and health care systems. In fact,
countries can subsidize the consumption of their own populations if they
merely need someone to buy their goods - they don’t have to pay consumers in
the United States to perform this task. The date at which foreign central
banks choose to stop subsidizing U.S. consumers cannot be concretely known,
but at some point it will happen.

The bad part of this story for South Korea is that the country is being
asked to give up a great deal to gain access to the shrinking U.S. import
market. The United States is pushing South Korea to weaken some of the
policies that have promoted the country’s extraordinary growth over the last
half-century. This includes eliminating restrictions on foreign investment
and strengthening protections for patents and copyrights, especially patent
protection for pharmaceuticals.

This last policy is especially pernicious because it is essentially an
effort to export a failed U.S. system to South Korea. The United States
currently spends more than US$700 a year per person for prescription drugs.
The high cost of drugs in the United States is one of the reasons why U.S.
health care costs are so much higher than in other countries. (The United
States spends more than twice as much per person as the average of other
wealthy countries, yet still ranks near the bottom in terms of life
expectancy.)

Patents have nothing to do with a "free market." They are in fact a form of
protectionism. Patents are a government granted monopoly, with the
government committing itself to arrest anyone who produces a patented drug
in competition with the patent holder.

Just as economic theory predicts, patent protection for drugs leads to a
wide variety of economic distortions, as well as outright corruption, as
drug companies attempt to maximize the value of this government monopoly.
There have been numerous incidents of drug companies making payoffs to deter
generic competitors, giving various types of kickbacks to doctors for
prescribing their drugs, and even falsifying evidence about the safety and
effectiveness of their drugs. In other words, the U.S. patent system for
prescription drugs is not one that other countries would want to copy.

Instead of enshrining patent protection, a relic of Europe’s feudal guild
system, in a "free trade" agreement it would be reasonable for South Korea
to seek out approaches to innovation that are more in tune with the 21st
Century. Alternatives such as government-financed research may be less
profitable to the U.S. pharmaceutical industry, but would likely lead to
better economic and healthcare outcomes for the Korean people.

Regarding intellectual property and other issues, Korea would be best served
if its leaders could think clearly about what a trade agreement with the
United States will offer in the future, rather than what it could have
offered in the past.


 source: Hankyoreh